Content:
July 8, 2002. James Love's presentation at the 14th Annual AIDS
Conference in Barcelona. An Essential
Health Care Patent Pool.
A “patent pool” is an agreement between two or more patent
owners to license one or more of their patents to one another or third
parties.
A patent pool may also be defined as “the aggregation of intellectual
property rights which are the subject of cross-licensing, whether they are
transferred directly by patentee to licensee or through some medium, such
as a joint venture, set up specifically to administer the patent pool.”
See Joel I. Klein, An Address to the
American Intellectual Property Law Association, on the Subject of
Cross-Licensing and Antitrust Law (May 2, 1997), (noting that United
States v. Line Materials , 333 U.S. 287, 313 n.24 (1948) states that the
term “patent pool” is not a term of art.)
Historically, to protect the public good, governments have created
collective rights organizations: mandating compulsory licensing of patents
at established fees, creating and managing public patent pools, directly
purchasing key enabling technology patents and placing them into the
public domain, and even creating mergers between firms. Private
institutions or industry-led consortia have also organized private patent
pools including small contract-based patent pools, large industry-wide
patent pools, and technology standard-setting patent pools.
In Institutions
For Intellectual Property Transactions: The Case for Patent Pools
(August 1999), Robert P. Merges writes:
In 1998, Sony, Philips and Pioneer formed a patent pool for
inventions that are essential to comply with certain DVD-Video and
DVD-ROM standard specifications.
In 1999, another patent pool was formed by Toshiba Corporation,
Hitachi, Ltd., Matsushita Electric Industrial Co., Ltd., Mitsubishi
Electric Corporation, Time Warner Inc., and Victor Company of Japan,
Ltd. for products manufactured in compliance with the DVD-ROM and
DVD-Video formats. See Letter from
Joel I. Klein, Assistant Attorney General, Department of Justice,
Antitrust Division, to Carey R. Ramos, Esq. (June 10, 1999)
DVD Patent Pool:
June 9-12, 20002. Panel: A Solution: Can Patent Pooling Uncork the
Technology Transfer Bottle Neck and Create Value? (International
Biotechnology Convention & Exhibition. Toronto, Ontario,
Canada).
February 8, 2002. Lawrence M. Sung. Greater
Predictability May Result in Patent Pools. Indeed, the vast amount of genetic information, and its
significance as a fundamental research tool even absent functional
knowledge, can give rise to an almost overwhelming number of patents,
the true value of which may be unascertainable without the cooperative
efforts of other companies. In any event, the overall transactional
costs associated with risk assessments based upon this relatively
uninformed valuation of patent rights may alone outweigh any perceived
benefit to the maintenance of an isolationist business strategy.[SNIP]
The fundamental features of a patent pool include the integration
of complementary technologies, the reduction of transaction costs, the
clearance of blocking patent positions and the avoidance of costly
infringement litigation. Its effectiveness springs principally from a
consensus among the participants that individual patent rights will be
made available to other members on fair, reasonable and
nondiscriminatory terms. In any event, the ability to obtain a
straightforward, reliable freedom to operate in an otherwise complex
arena of intellectual property will be a dominant appeal of a
biotechnology patent pool for prospective participants and nonmember
licensees alike.
Given the dynamics of biotechnology research and development, the
reliance by the industry on cooperative market-based technology
transfer strategies through patent pools or other CROs may be
inevitable. If so, the prospects for future success will likely depend
on the swift acceptance and implementation of such collective rights
programs.
The Division's decisions rested on a number of factors, including
the fact that the pools license only those patents essential for a
manufacturer to comply with an established standard. The pools were
designed to capture the efficiencies that may come from licensing
complementary technologies. Concomitantly, they were designed to
limit the anticompetitive effect that can arise from pooling
technology, such as the elimination of competition or the increase
in prices that could arise if substitute technologies (that is,
technologies that could compete against each other) were placed in a
pool.
In these hearings, we will encourage exploration of a number of
broad questions about patents pools, such as whether pools actually
result in the competitive problems they are hypothesized to cause
and whether the antitrust authorities have focused on the right
criteria when evaluating patent pools.
Essential Inventions, Inc. on Collective Management of IP Rights: Patent
Pool
What
is a Patent Pool?
Patent
Pool Examples
Patent
Pool and Antitrust Laws
Selected
Documents and Links on Patent Pool
Patent
Pool in the News
Essential Inventions Home
What is a Patent Pool?
A patent pool is an arrangement among multiple patent
holders to aggregate their patents. A typical pool makes all pooled
patents available to each member of the pool. Pools also usually offer
standard licensing terms to licensees who are not members of the pool.
In addition, the typical patent pool allocates a portion of the
licensing fees to each member according to a pre-set formula or
procedure [...] Of course, there is one major difference between private
collectives and conventional, statutory compulsory licenses: in these
organizations, the members, and not Congress or a court, set the price.
This almost always involves extensive negotiations; sometimes, ongoing
adjustments are carried out via a permanent administrative structure.
The point is, however, that the collective organizations present a
simple, coherent menu of prices and other terms to licensees – and that
they do so after extensive internal consultation.
Patent Pool Examples
In 1856, the Sewing Machine Combination formed one of the first
patent pools consisting of sewing machine patents. See Robert P.
Merges, Institutions
For Intellectual Property Transactions: The Case for Patent Pools
(August 1999).
In 1908, Armat, Biograph, Edison and Vitagraph entered an
agreement under which the four firms assigned "all the patents in the
early-day motion picture industry." The agreement also specified the
royalties that were to be paid into the pool by licensees of the pool
patents such as movie exhibitors. More on the history at: The
Edison Movie Monopoly: The Motion Picture Patents Company vs.the
Independent Outlaws by J. A. Aberdeen, The First
Studios by Marc Wanamakert, Archives
of Universal Studios: Carl Laemmle and the Early Years of
Universal and The
Business of the Movies by Rich Warms.
In 1916, the owners of various patents related to folding beds and
other similar devices entered into an agreement providing exclusive
license to the Seng Company to manufacture and sell under the pool
patents. Of the total royalties, 33 percent was alloted to the Pullman
Couch Company. The license contract was signed by the Davoplane Bed
Company (7 patents), the Pullman Couch Company (13 patents) and two
inventors. The Seng Company paid a fixed percentage to the pool. Pool
members split the royalty according to a formula in the pooling
agreement.
In 1917, as a result of a recommendation of a committee formed by
the Assistant Secretary of the Navy (The Honorable Franklin D.
Roosevelt), an aircraft
patent pool was privately formed encompassing almost all aircraft
manufacturers in the United States. The creation of the Manufacturer’s
Aircraft Association was crucial to the U.S. government because the
two major patent holders, the Wright Company and the Curtiss Company,
had effectively blocked the building of any new airplanes, which were
desperately needed as the United States was entering World War I. See
Harry T. Dykman, Patent Licensing within The Manufacturer’s Aircraft
Association (MAA), 46 J. PAT. OFF. SOC’Y 646, 648 (1964).
DVD Licensing Site. DVD6C Licensing Agency. There are
presently 80 U. S. Patents for DVD-ROM drives, DVD-Video players and
DVD decoders, and 96 U. S. Patents for DVD-ROM discs and DVD-Video
discs. The royalties under the joint license for DVD-Video players and
DVD-ROM drives are 4% of the net selling price of the product or U.S.
$4.00 per product, whichever is higher. Royalties for DVD decoders are
4% of the net selling price of the product or U.S. $1.00 per product,
whichever is higher (more
information).
The basic idea behind OpenPatents.org is to change
the rules of the patent game such that it is to the advantage of
participants to help solve the problems of software patents.
December 1999. Katherine Moore, Ph.D., Ethics Advisory Committee.
Sharing
Genetic Research Tools, The Ethical Considerations.
This article refers
to biotechnology inventions to include isolated genetic molecules,
such as DNA or RNA, and biologics produced through recombinant
technology.
Patent Pool and Antitrust Laws
Selected Documents and Links on Patent Pool
In the late 1990s, the Division examined through the
Business Review process three different proposals to jointly license
patents to other companies, an MPEG patent pool (a video compression
technology) and two DVD patent pools. In all three cases, the
Division concluded that the proposed arrangements did not appear to
pose antitrust concerns.
The paper compares
compulsory patent licensing provisions in the United States and
modern, foreign nations.
In March 1998, the FTC announced charges against Summit
Technology, Inc. and VISX, Inc. regarding their pooling of patents
related to photorefractive keratectomy ("PRK"). PRK is a form of eye
surgery that uses lasers to reshape the cornea and frees many people
from the need to wear glasses or contact lenses. They were the only
firms with the US Food and Drug Administration ("FDA") approval to
market PRK equipment. They licensed most of their PRK patents to a
shell entity named Pillar Point Partnership.(61) This partnership then
licensed the full portfolio of patents back to Summit and VISX, and
only to Summit and VISX. Summit and VISX sold or leased PRK equipment
to eye doctors and sublicensed the doctors to perform PRK procedures.
The patent pooling arrangement required Summit and VISX to pay the
Partnership a $250 fee each time a PRK procedure was performed. Summit
and VISX, in turn, charged each of their respective sublicensees a
$250 per-procedure fee. Neither Summit nor VISX had an incentive to
reduce this fee because the patent pooling agreement obligated each
firm to pay this amount to the pool. See for more
details.
SUMMARY:
A British drug manufacturer held an American patent on the dosage form
of griseofulvin, a fungicide, and another British drug manufacturer
held an American patent on a microsize dosage form of griseofulvin.
The two manufacturers made a patent pooling agreement containing
certain restrictions on the sale of bulk-form griseofulvin. Similar
bulk-sale restrictions were contained in sublicensing agreements made
by the two manufacturers with three American drug companies. In a
civil antitrust action in the United States District Court for the
District of Columbia, the United States Government sought to enjoin
enforcement of the bulk-sale restrictions on the ground that they
involved unreasonable restraints of trade, in violation of 1 of the
Sherman Act. Also, the government challenged the validity of the
American patents which had been obtained by the British manufacturers.
The District Court held that the bulk-sales restrictions constituted
per se violations of 1 of the Sherman Act, but that since the
manufacturers were not relying on the patents in defense of the
government's antitrust claims, the government could not challenge the
validity of the patents (302 F Supp 1). Although the District Court
granted the government's request for injunctive relief against future
violations, the District Court denied the government's request that
the manufacturers be ordered (1) to make bulk sales on reasonable and
nondiscriminatory terms and prices to all bona fide applicants, and
(2) to grant reasonable-royalty licenses for the manufacture of
griseofulvin (328 F Supp 709).
SUMMARY: The validity of provisions of a decree in an
anti-trust suit in which patent abuses were proved, for compulsory
licensing of the use of the patented inventions, giving lessees an
option to purchase leased machines, and the action of the trial judge
in leaving the matter of royalties to a committee, reserving to
himself the casting vote in case of deadlock, are approved by eight
members of the Court in an opinion by Jackson, J.
These various institutions [industry-wide pools] have
differed materially in the type of organization created by the
agreements. Perhaps the loosest of all is the automobile
manufacturers agreement, and obvious [sic] the most severe
restrictions are imposed where the patents pass into the hands of a
single owner, yet all these agreements have in common the principle
that within the industry, the individual monopoly created by patents
is abolished in the form it is provided by statute and a different
system is substituted more in harmony with the needs of that
industry.
[I]n the airplane cross-licensing agreement, after
completely abolishing the monopoly of the individual inventor and
opening every patent to every member of the association, it provides
that a board of arbitrators may decide in any case what reward
should be paid to individual patent owners and this is based not
upon the official determination of patentability by the Patent
Office, but upon the unofficial determination of the importance of
the invention by a board of arbitrators (quoted by Merges
19).
Patent Pool in the News